November 3, 2014 Reading Time: 2 minutes

In last week’s briefing, The Economist magazine worries that current spending on consumption and investment will fall if individuals believe money will be more valuable in the future.

There are several issues with this position. First, focusing on deflation obscures the real concern. Deflation is not a cause, but a consequence. Yes, central banks might fail to adjust the money supply to offset increases in money demand. But, as the Economist admits, deflation might also result from productivity growth. It is only the former monetary deflation that we should fear.

Second, the author fails to distinguish expected from unexpected monetary deflation. Consumption and investment only contract if individuals must reduce spending to maintain desired real money balances. In the case of expected monetary deflation, falling prices allow individuals to maintain real money balances without consuming or investing less. Just as expected money growth merely produces inflation (i.e., without significantly affecting what we are able to produce), an expected monetary contraction merely causes prices to fall. Neutrality isn’t strictly true in either case (see below, for example). But no serious macroeconomist believes the path to prosperity starts at the printing press.

Finally, the Economist ignores the potential benefits of mild monetary deflation. Milton Friedman once argued that we do not hold enough money when the purchasing power falls each period, since bonds and other less liquid assets allow us to avoid the inflation tax. He maintained that we would hold the optimum quantity of money only if the purchasing power were to increase each period at a rate that makes the return on money just equal to the return on other risk-free assets. In other words, mild monetary deflation would promote exchange and production by removing the inflation tax and putting money on equal footing with other risk free assets.

Don’t get me wrong: money matters. Inflation is costly. Deflation is costly. Unexpected nominal shocks (i.e., changes in money supply not supported by changes in money demand) can generate a cluster of errors—unsustainable (and undesirable) booms, in the case of nominal expansions, and unnecessary slumps, in the case of nominal contractions. The effects are real. But we must understand the underlying mechanisms at play so that we can distinguish the consequential from the inconsequential.

William J. Luther

William J. Luther

William J. Luther is the Director of AIER’s Sound Money Project and an Associate Professor of Economics at Florida Atlantic University. His research focuses primarily on questions of currency acceptance. He has published articles in leading scholarly journals, including Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Economic Inquiry, Journal of Institutional Economics, Public Choice, and Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. His popular writings have appeared in The Economist, Forbes, and U.S. News & World Report. His work has been featured by major media outlets, including NPR, Wall Street Journal, The Guardian, TIME Magazine, National Review, Fox Nation, and VICE News. Luther earned his M.A. and Ph.D. in Economics at George Mason University and his B.A. in Economics at Capital University. He was an AIER Summer Fellowship Program participant in 2010 and 2011.

Get notified of new articles from William J. Luther and AIER.