August 18, 2020 Reading Time: 4 minutes
stormy fed

Politicians have recently called on the Federal Reserve to address issues of racial and income inequality. Current and former Fed officials have pointed out that monetary policy is too broad a tool to accomplish this narrow goal. Yet the Fed may have the ability to affect inequality by other, more effective means.

Presidential candidate Joe Biden has recommended that “the Fed should aggressively enhance its surveillance and targeting of persistent racial gaps in jobs, wages, and wealth.” A similar proposal by Senator Elizabeth Warren would require the Fed to pursue “the elimination of disparities across racial and ethnic groups with respect to employment, income, wealth, and access to affordable credit.”

Improving the livelihoods of minorities and low-income earners is a noble goal. Economists widely agree, however, that these objectives cannot be achieved using monetary policy.

Inequality is a long-term, structural issue that cannot be resolved with monetary policy, as former Fed Chairs Ben Bernanke and Janet Yellen have acknowledged. “The degree of inequality we see today,” Bernanke said, “is primarily the result of deep structural changes in our economy that have taken place over many years.” Because “monetary policy is a blunt tool,” Bernanke argued that “policies designed to affect the distribution of wealth and income are, appropriately, the province of elected officials, not the Fed.”

In 2016 Congressional testimony, Yellen similarly emphasized the broad nature of monetary policy. “A stronger labor market,” she said, “will improve the status of all groups in the labor market.” But addressing inequality is more difficult since “there are deeper structural reasons that these trends continue.”

Current Fed Chair Jerome Powell also recently expressed skepticism regarding the Fed’s ability to deal with income inequality. Noting the broad nature of monetary policy, he said that “a tight labor market is probably the best thing that the Fed can foster to go after that problem.” Powell emphasized that Congress, rather than the Fed, may be more equipped to deal with issues of inequality. “We don’t really have tools that can address distributional disparate outcomes as well as fiscal policy.”

The Fed does, however, have another means by which it can combat inequality. It could eliminate excess regulations that inhibit bank competition and the hiring of low-skilled workers.

Standard economics teaches that regulations tend to reduce competition and economic efficiency. Until the 1990s, US banks were generally prohibited from opening branches in other states and sometimes even within their home state. These restrictions made the banking industry less efficient, resulting in higher costs for bank customers. Restrictions on branch banking also make it difficult to diversify investments, which makes the banking system less stable.

From the 1970s through the 1990s, many states eliminated branch banking restrictions, allowing greater competition in the banking industry. Studies of this period find that eliminating these state-level regulations lowered loan rates for borrowers, improved entrepreneurship, and reduced economic volatility

In a 2010 study, Thorsten Beck, Ross Levine, and Alexey Levkov consider whether deregulations during this period affected income inequality. They look at several measures of inequality such as the Gini coefficient, Theil index, and the ratio of the 90th to 10th percentiles of income. The evidence shows that “branch deregulation substantially reduced income inequality.”

The authors are careful to account for other effects that might bias their results. They control for local economic conditions, such as state-level unemployment rates and GDP growth, demographic differences, such as the percentages of blacks and female-headed households, and other policies, such as labor market reforms. The results consistently show that bank deregulation reduced inequality.

Beck, Levine, and Levkov also test whether reductions in inequality are driven by changes at the low or high ends of the income distribution. Their results, reproduced in the figure below, find that deregulation was associated with gains to the lower levels of the income distribution without significant effects on higher levels of the distribution.

They further examine the timing of effects on workers at the lowest income levels. As seen in the figure below, the relative real wages of unskilled workers increased considerably in the years following deregulation. Bank deregulation also appears to have boosted employment opportunities as illustrated by lower rates of unemployment and higher working hours for unskilled workers.

Bank deregulation since the 1970s has had important economic effects of reducing income inequality and improving economic stability. The evidence suggests that, unlike monetary policy, deregulation is one avenue by which the Fed might have meaningful effects on reducing income inequality.

To be clear: I am not recommending bank regulators relax their emphasis on bank safety and soundness. Regulators must always remain focused on financial stability, but trimming excess regulations would reduce barriers to entry for new banks and ease the regulatory burdens of smaller banks that pose no risk to the banking system. A study by Richard Herring, for instance, found that bank capital regulations “could be reduced by 75% with no loss of rigor.”

In fact, reducing the number of regulations can often be more effective at constraining bank risk. In the same way that a complex tax code creates loopholes to avoid the law, a complex regulatory system enables banks to avoid compliance. Strong but simple regulations can improve financial stability without creating undue costs of regulatory compliance.

Nor am I suggesting that racial disparities be made a primary focus of regulation. Efforts by the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) to target discriminatory lending practices, for example, have made lending to minorities more costly and less common. A more prudent approach is to eliminate unnecessary barriers to competition. Such a change is likely to increase opportunities for those with lower incomes and narrow the wage gap between low-skilled and high-skilled workers.

Economic theory suggests, and evidence confirms, that the burden of regulations is likely to fall on the least well-off members of society. Limiting regulation encourages competition in the banking system, resulting in lower costs for consumers and more hiring of low-skilled workers.

If the Fed aims to reduce inequality, it should use policies that are known to be effective. There is little scope for affecting inequality with monetary policy. Reducing banks’ regulatory burden reduces inequality by improving the lives of Americans with the lowest incomes.  

Thomas L. Hogan

Thomas L. Hogan, Ph.D., is senior research fellow at AIER. He was formerly the chief economist for the U.S. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs. He has also worked at Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy, Troy University, West Texas A&M University, the Cato Institute, the World Bank, Merrill Lynch’s commodity trading group and for investment firms in the U.S. and Europe. Dr. Hogan’s research has been published in academic journals such as the Journal of Macroeconomics and the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. He has appeared on programs such as BBC World News, Stossel TV, and Bloomberg Radio and has been quoted by news outlets including CNN Business, American Banker, and the National Review.

Get notified of new articles from Thomas L. Hogan and AIER.